A Crisis of Reserves

The Antiplanner continues to read recent books about the 2008 financial crisis, but there are definite diminishing returns. I just finished Roger Lowenstein‘s The End of Wall Street and found it disappointing. It covered almost exactly the same ground as Too Big to Fail, but unlike the latter book, which was based mainly on interviews, Lowenstein’s book seems to be based heavily on articles and op eds in various newspapers and magazines.

The book is poorly referenced–sometimes a citation to a critical point lists nothing more than a person’s name–and somewhat superficial in its description of complex events. Lowenstein focuses heavily on subprime mortgages, but (as I’ll explain in detail in a later post) I don’t think they were the real problem. “Rampant speculation (and abuse) in mortgages was surely the primary cause of the bubble,” he concludes, but he doesn’t even sound like he believes it. There was just as much mortgage “abuse” in Texas as in California, yet Texas had no bubble. Rampant speculation only takes place after prices are already rapidly rising, so such speculation by itself can’t have caused the bubble.

I did learn one important point. Earlier I noted that Jeffrey Friedman argues that SEC rules that gave three companies–Moody’s, Standard & Poors, and Fitch–a legal oligopoly in rating securities was a major problem. I questioned whether more competition would have made any difference since ratings were purchased by bond sellers, and the sellers would just go to companies that gave them the ratings they liked. It would be better, I suggested, if buyers paid for the ratings rather than sellers.

It turns out Friedman and I are both right. Before the oligopoly, Lowenstein notes, bond buyers did pay for ratings (through subscription services). It was only after the oligopoly was created that the ratings companies found it more lucrative to be paid by security sellers (pp. 39-40). If Friedman had made that point, I missed it, and it would have helped his argument make a lot more sense.

Lowenstein makes another important point that supports what I’ve concluded from reading many other books: “The root of the crisis,” he says, “was that every bank in the Western world had orders to reduce leverage” (p. 257). What does this mean?

The recent financial crisis has been called a crisis of confidence. One day, banks and other financial institutions had faith in each other; the next day, they did not and so they stopped lending. If only everyone’s confidence could have been restored, the reasoning goes, there would have been no crisis. Unfortunately (or fortunately, if you want to believe the system is less fragile than that), that’s wrong.

The crisis has also been called a crisis of liquidity. The banks had the money they needed, but it just wasn’t liquid. They made the mistake of “borrowing short and lending long,” i.e., borrowing on short-term (such as 45-day) notes and lending for 15 to 30 years or more. At some point, the owners of the short-term notes asked for their money back, but the banks couldn’t pay for 15 to 30 years. The remedy would seem to be simple: pass rules preventing banks from borrowing short and lending long. However, that wasn’t the real problem either.

The crisis has also been called a result of the system being too big or too interconnected to fail. AIG owed close to $100 billion to each of twelve major banks. If AIG failed, those banks could fail too, followed by all the other financial institutions that they owed money to. But healthy systems are always interconnected; being too big or too interconnected was not the real core of the problem.

Another explanation is that this was a crisis of solvency. Banks such as CitiGroup and Lehman Brothers were overleveraged, meaning a small decline in the value of their assets, such as mortgage bonds, would render their net values negative. AIG, which had insured those mortgage bonds, didn’t have the cash to pay out that insurance. While this was a real problem, it isn’t what caused the financial meltdown experienced in fall of 2008.
Men experiencing feebleness and erectile brokenness or impotency. cialis 10mg The most common sexual health issue facing men is erectile dysfunction. cheap viagra no rx Men bearing this thwarting situation must stay soft generic viagra away from sipping alcohol and fatty foods items before gulping down this drug. Pain disorders, headaches, low back pain all these problems and prevents recurrence cheap viagra usa in future.
The real problem was a crisis of reserves. Banks are intermediaries; they borrow money from some and lend it to others. Bankers have long known that they can’t lend all their money out because some of the people they borrow it from may want it back before the people they lend it to pay it back. So they keep some cash or some other liquid form of money such as Treasury bills in reserve.

Banks that accept deposits face legal reserve requirements that are risk adjusted. If a bank lends money to a corporation, it needs to keep 8 percent of the loan in reserve. Mortgages are supposed to be less risky than corporations, so if a bank lends to a homebuyer, it needs to keep only 4 percent in reserve. Government-sponsored enterprises such as Fannie Mae are supposed to be even less risky, so if a bank buys Fannie Mae bonds, it needs to keep only 1.6 percent in reserve.

Investment banks, which deal with stocks and bonds, faced less government regulation, but instead were regulated by the market. Contracts would specify, for example, lower reserve requirements for buyers of a triple-A rated bond or securities from a triple-A rated company and higher requirements for AA-, A-, or B-rated bonds or securities. If a company is downgraded, its collateral increases, meaning it must put up more cash than before.

A bank could therefore increase its leverage–the amount of money it lends out relative to the amount it keeps in reserve–by lending to homebuyers, selling the mortgages to Fannie or Freddie, then buying bonds from Fannie or Freddie. They could also securitize the mortgages–package a thousand or so into a bond–and sell the bonds. Once off their books, they didn’t have to count them, but even on their books, with most such bonds being rated triple-A, they only had to keep minimal reserves.

The crisis came about because companies misjudged the reserves or collateral required for the mortgages, bonds, and other securities they were trading. The ratings agencies overestimated the safety of mortgage bonds. AIG and other insurers overestimated the safety of the insurance policies they were providing on those bonds.

When the housing market peaked in 2006, the ratings agencies realized they had overrated mortgage bonds and started downgrading the bonds. This forced the deposit banks that owned the bonds to increase their reserve requirements to legal levels. Some, such as CitiBank, owned so many bonds that they could not possibly come up with enough cash to fulfill their reserve requirements.

Investment banks, such as Bear Stearns and Lehman Brothers, faced collateral calls from the banks, such as JPMorgan Chase, that they had borrowed money from. When they couldn’t meet those calls, they went broke.

AIG had insured around $50 billion of mortgage bonds. It thought those bonds were perfectly safe so it failed to provide any reserves for that insurance. AIG was a wealthy company, one of the few to enjoy a triple-A corporate rating, but most of its assets were tied up in reserves for its various state insurance subsidiaries. As the ratings agencies downgraded the mortgage bonds, they also threatened to downgrade AIG’s corporate rating. Under the contracts for its mortgage insurance (credit default swaps), a single downgrade would require AIG to put $10 billion in cash–cash it didn’t have–to provide assurance that it could meet its obligations.

All of these changes in reserve requirements and collateral calls put banks and other institutions behind the eight-ball: suddenly they needed more cash than they had. They couldn’t lend out money because they needed all the money they had to fill their reserves. They couldn’t borrow money because everyone else was also scrambling to meet their reserve requirements.

Understanding that the immediate cause of the meltdown was a crisis of reserves, and that this crisis stemmed from the downgrading of mortgage bonds by the ratings agencies, is critical to understanding the underlying cause of the crisis. I discuss that in detail in a future post.

Bookmark the permalink.

About The Antiplanner

The Antiplanner is a forester and economist with more than fifty years of experience critiquing government land-use and transportation plans.

15 Responses to A Crisis of Reserves

  1. aloysius9999 says:

    Is “risk management” a four letter word unfit for a family audience?

    Yes, the banks didn’t have the reserves, but wasn’t much of it because they outsourced risk management to the rating agencies and to Fredi and Fannie.

  2. aloysius9999,

    Banks sold some of their mortgages to Fannie and Freddie. But they converted most mortgages to mortgage bonds and sold those to other investors. The problem was that they kept lending and turning mortgages into mortgage bonds after the peak of the bubble. Investors stopped buying the bonds and the banks were stuck with lots of overvalued mortgages on their hands. Also, Citibank never did sell all of their bonds and instead kept many on their books, so it was in the direst straits of any of the major banks.

  3. C. P. Zilliacus says:

    The Antiplanner wrote:

    Understanding that the immediate cause of the meltdown was a crisis of reserves, and that this crisis stemmed from the downgrading of mortgage bonds by the ratings agencies, is critical to understanding the underlying cause of the crisis. I discuss that in detail in a future post.

    But wasn’t a root cause of the above the so-called “subprime” mortgage home loans to people who had no possibility of every re-paying what they had borrowed?

  4. bennett says:

    C. P. Zilliacus says: “But wasn’t a root cause of the above the so-called “subprime” mortgage home loans to people who had no possibility of every re-paying what they had borrowed?”

    I read something this weekend (looking for the link) that was an analysis of a statistically significance number of defaulted “subprime” loans. The findings showed that many (about 1/4 of the sample) had the income to pay off what they borrowed had they gotten into a standard home loan. For these people it was the ratcheting and usury interest rates that did them in. What the article could not attest to was the reason why these people couldn’t get a standard home loan in the first place. On speculation the author thought that bad credit, lack of understanding of finance and/or predatory lending practices were possible causes.

    Aside: There is still a radio add here in Austin selling subprime loans. It goes something like, “If you KNOW your going to be out of the house in 5 years or less, we have a deal for you… If you think you’ll be there for more then 5 years do settle in for a normal loan.”

  5. metrosucks says:

    it was the ratcheting and usury interest rates that did them in

    But these people were aware of the rates they agreed to. It’s not as if they went in blind. Now, perhaps the bankers should have made the risks of say, an adjustable rate mortgage more clear, but apparently everyone was asleep at the wheel anyway.

  6. bennett says:

    metrosucks says: “But these people were aware of the rates they agreed to. It’s not as if they went in blind…”

    Maybe, maybe not. No excuse either way. The point is that for this specific cohort, had they obtained a more standard loan they would have not defaulted. I don’t attribute any more blame to bankers or lendees, but lets face it… the major banks set up contracts for credit to screw the customer. You have to be diligent and savvy (or just avoid debt all together) not to get screwed by them. A few months ago Wells Fargo tried to take $40 out of my savings account because I had not made a withdrawal or deposit in the last four months. It was eventually returned after the telephone run-around, but we all have personal examples of how these institutions are set up to crush those without the time, money and wherewithal to fight back.

  7. Dan says:

    Investment banks, such as Bear Stearns and Lehman Brothers, faced collateral calls from the banks, such as JPMorgan Chase, that they had borrowed money from. When they couldn’t meet those calls, they went broke.

    Yes. When I worked for the bank, part of my job was to provide reports showing that we were meeting federal requirements for reserves, risk, etc.

    When the regulations were relaxed by Congress and Clinton, it wasn’t our class of bank that went crazy, it was the big investment houses that were allowed to get their grubby hands in many more pies. Then they created all these “instruments” to cover their tracks. Lots bought into the bubble.

    That is the gist of what happened. Bankers are kept in control for a reason. It might be too late in this country, as there may be a plutocracy already in place, with FIRE a major player.

    DS

  8. CPZ,

    No, subprimes were not the cause of the crisis. They were more of a symptom. When housing prices declined, the main defaults were people who had good credit but whose home values had fallen to less than their mortgage.

    The crisis happened because the ratings companies and, in turn, companies buying and insuring mortgage bonds believed that prices would never decline. When prices did decline, the triple-A rates declined with them and suddenly lots of banks and insurers needed to set aside lots of money as collateral and reserves that they didn’t have.

    Dan,

    You are right that the investment houses legally had lower reserves than the banks. But several investment houses — notably Goldman Sachs — did not get into serious trouble, while several banks — notably Citibank — did. After the crisis, all of the big surviving investment banks changed to “holding banks,” which means they are now under pretty much the same rules as regular banks.

  9. the highwayman says:

    Bennet: We all have personal examples of how these institutions are set up to crush those without the time, money and wherewithal to fight back.

    THWM: Indeed, there isn’t much of a difference between the private sector & the public sector. Also it’s those that have the least that pay the most.

  10. Frank says:

    “…Jeffrey Friedman argues that SEC rules that gave three companies–Moody’s, Standard & Poors, and Fitch–a legal oligopoly in rating securities was a major problem.Jeffrey Friedman argues that SEC rules that gave three companies–Moody’s, Standard & Poors, and Fitch–a legal oligopoly in rating securities was a major problem.”

    Speaking of the oligarchs’ right-hand man the S&P, you should check in with Peter Schiff. Recall that he was the guy who predicted this mess.

    His best-seller: Crash Proof: How to Profit From the Coming Economic Collapse. (I took his advise and quadrupled my investment in two years.)

    His recent take on today’s S&P announcement:

    Text: Late to The Party…Once Again

    Video: S & P: As Always, Late to the Party!

    “Peter Schiff was right!” could become the modern-day equivalent to “Who is John Galt?”

  11. Dan says:

    But several investment houses — notably Goldman Sachs — did not get into serious trouble, while several banks — notably Citibank — did.

    Apologies if I conflated risk and reserves.

    DS

  12. bennett says:

    I can’t think of anything that goes against my intuition more than credit ratings whether it’s Moody’s, S&P or the nebulous boogiemen that rate me. It seems to be in direct conflict with basic economic and capitalistic principals.

  13. Dan says:

    Rational utility maximizing agents need information to judge credit-worthiness.

    DS

  14. Frank says:

    Yes, unbiased information from reliable sources. (Read: not from oligarchs.)

  15. bennett says:

    …and information that is also available to the consumer/borrower. Credit rating agencies have a monopoly on information that they are unwilling to share (or unwilling to share at a reasonable price).

Leave a Reply