Some researchers from Vanderbilt University (and one from Cornell) asked what will happen to traffic congestion after the pandemic. If people reduced the use of transit for commuting, they concluded, congestion will get a lot worse, which is “detrimental to everyone’s commute.” Though they never say so explicitly, the implication is that we need to spend a lot of money supporting transit agencies to prevent that congestion.
Yet their paper is greatly oversimplified and ignores many things. Most importantly, people working at home are going to make a bigger difference to congestion than transit riders. Before the pandemic, more people worked at home than rode transit to work. If after the pandemic the number of people working at home on any given day is double what it was before the pandemic, then there would be less traffic even if no one rode transit.
In fact, the number of people working home is likely to much more than double. More than 40 percent of workers are working at home due to the pandemic, and at least a quarter of those say they expect to continue working at home after than pandemic. That would triple what it was before the pandemic. Moreover, half of those who expect to continue working at home say they will move to a different location, generally a suburb or smaller city.
The paper also ignores the fact that people adjust their behavior in response to congestion. One of the lead authors of the paper, Dan Work, was quoted as saying, “Road-building is an expensive proposition that doesn’t solve the underlying issue of high commute times in the long term.”
This claim is based on Anthony Downs’ “triple-convergence” theory, which is that people respond to congestion by changing their routes, the time of day that they commute, or their modes; when new roads relieve congestion, then some of them will change back and the roads appear as congested as they were before. (In fact, while they may be just as congested at peak hour, they are usually congested for fewer hours of the day.)
In this case, infertility treatment usually requires surgery, particularly if the immune system is weak, drug treatment may fail, or the doctor may recommend surgery to get levitra for sale online rid of infected tissues. Muscles get relaxed when the viagra sale visit content brain sends signals to male organ. They clog the penile muscles & routes of the male reproductive organ & therein, it obstructs the proper flow of the blood viagra uk along the male reproductive system. Notwithstanding, discount viagra usa will be more expensive than other brands.This product can’t work with men who have acquired physical damage to their penile area.You cannot take this drug if you are suffering from diabetes will eventually face nerve damage.
If you believe that the presence or absence of new roads doesn’t make a difference for congestion, then it also must be true that the presence or absence of transit doesn’t make much of a difference to congestion. In other words, if you don’t believe new roads can relieve congestion, then you cannot possibly believe that transit relieves congestion.
More particularly, people will respond to any congestion after the pandemic in the same way they responded before. The economy is not going to recover overnight, but as it recovers people will decide what to do about congestion for themselves, whether by changing their routes, times of travel, or modes.
Some will respond by changing their work locations. Several company heads have already said they expect to move people from crowded cities to the suburbs or smaller towns. That will relieve congestion as much as letting more people work at home.
Transit is going to suffer a huge loss of riders. Instead of wringing hands over the future of this industry that was already obsolete and all but irrelevant (except as a tax burden) in most cities, it’s time to figure out how to reinvent it so it isn’t a money pit and is actually doing some good.
There is really nothing to this analysis. It is a crude, macroscopic simulation that just assumes that transit users will switch to single-occupant driving during peak periods and will thus result in worse congestion.
Apart from Randal’s comment about telecommuting being the more likely behavioral shift once the virus subsides, there are also other reasons to be highly skeptical of any doomsday scenario. For one thing, their model doesn’t consider possible adjustments in trip timing to avoid the most congested periods, something many commuters already do to limit the impact of congestion on their trip. Also, the model ignores other choice dimensions that are typically included in demand forecasting models (destination choice, mode choice).
This paper is what happens when a group of non-transportation researchers naively apply a mathematical model that is not fit to answer the question they propose. But then again, given their conclusion, it sounds like they already knew the answer they were looking for. The analysis is just elaborate window dressing.
Oh, I also just noticed that they assumed away the existence of transportation networks, so route switching is also eliminated as a possible response to congestion.
And this work was supposedly funded by the National Science Foundation. Embarrassing.
As with most research funded by the government or various large foundations, the research is performed not to investigate or find facts – but to prove a predetermined result.
They wrote the result first and then found (or created) the research to prove their conclusions.
“If you believe that the presence or absence of new roads doesn’t make a difference for congestion, then it also must be true that the presence or absence of transit doesn’t make much of a difference to congestion. In other words, if you don’t believe new roads can relieve congestion, then you cannot possibly believe that transit relieves congestion.”
Indeed. Transit / public transport reduces congestion in the short term, but then additional development and elasticity effects eliminate the congestion benefits. Keeping the traffic below about 80% of capacity and regulating development mode shares would work. Once you are close to capacity it is hard to fix anything due to price elasticity.
“…it’s time to figure out how to reinvent it so it isn’t a money pit and is actually doing some good.”
The book that you need is this one:
Transport for Suburbia
Paul Mees
ISBN 978-1-844907-740-3
This explains why some wealthy, low density, areas have very effective public transport. Thought provoking.